Optis v Apple Trial E (Part I): findings on specific issues and topics


This is Trial E, one of the six related trials between Optis and Apple. Trials A – D are technical trials about the validity and/or essentiality of certain patents (the Judge in Trial E observed that the sample in these technical trials was too small to allow him to draw any conclusion as to the quality of Optis’ Portfolio; also, that the decisions of very experienced first instance judges varied on appeal, showing that the outcomes of questions of essentiality and validity are nuanced and extremely difficult to predict: [188]). Trial F concerned the issues of whether Apple was permanently disentitled from relying on Optis’ ETSI undertaking and thus may be subject to an unqualified injunction and some of Apple's defences to this; the appeal from it will be heard by the UK Supreme Court. Trial E determined in particular the terms of a FRAND licence and the conduct of the parties in the negotiations. The Judgment, [2023] EWHC 1095 (Ch), is not available from the BAILII website, but Managing IP uploaded a copy here.





This Kat’s notes on the Judgment has two parts: the second part will concern the FRAND Question and this first part contains everything else.


Findings on specific issues and topics


Data regarding the stack

 

Data regarding the stack could not be obtained directly from ETSI. Apple relied on data from Innography and Optis, from PA Consulting ([111] – [112], after abandoning all the evidence of a witness, Ms Dwyer). But the Judge considered them to be problematic: he was presented with no one from either PA Consulting or Innography to speak to this data, and there was a significant amount of evidence suggesting that no third party study was of any particular help ([114] – [115]).


Innography data were broadly speaking reliable, partly because Optis did not adduce any evidence to challenge the reliability of the Innography database ([133]; see also [132]).


PA Consulting reviewed only essentiality and not validity ([118]). Their conclusions were enormously unreliable, given the mass of patent families in play and given the difficulty of the exercise ([122]). Moreover, validity should also have been taken into account, because a qualitative approach to the stack and to portions within the stack only makes sense if both essentiality and validity are factored in ([123], i). The Judge observed that the number of SEPs declared to a standard is more reliable than the more qualitative assessments which seek to exclude from the stack declared SEPs that are invalid or not essential ([136], i). Further, PA Consulting filtered for essentiality which was a judgmental exercise. Making a judgement about the levels of essentiality in the stack is unreliable and unsafe ([136], iii).


The Judge accordingly concluded that the PA Consulting/Optis approach to determining the stack size was not reliable ([137]).


The quality of the Portfolio


Judging from the evidence, validity was not really considered in the selection process the Optis Portfolio underwent ([150], iii). Because there is no effective way of testing the essentiality, validity, and importance of each patent in a portfolio, having a lot of declared patents overall makes logical sense ([158], iv). Optis asserted privilege on some documents that would confirm or gainsay some of the assertions as to the Portfolio quality, which means that these assertions could not be tested in cross-examination ([161]). There was no material on which the Judge could conclude that Optis’ Portfolio was anything other than average [162]).


The Judge saw no assurance that the essentiality rates put forward by Optis at trial and in licencing negotiations were defensible ([169]).


Based on the evidence the Judge noted that the Portfolio was assembled in the following way: some litigation grade patents were included to make good any claim in the courts on validity or essentiality; some to read onto specifications to enrich the quality or apparent quality of the pool; and some makeweights ([177]).


The conclusion on the quality of the Optis Portfolio was that there was no credible evidence to prove that the Portfolio was above average in strength, either regarding essentiality or validity ([182]).


General approach to negotiating licences: Optis


Before the hand-down of Unwired Planet (First Instance) [2017] EWHC 2988 (Pat) Optis’ rates were excessive ([193]). Optis had an unwavering commitment to ad valorem rates ([199]). They tended not to record discussions and to conduct business orally and without documentation. They relied to a considerable degree various rates tied to and sought to leverage Unwired Planet (First Instance) Judgment and jurisdiction. And the Birss rate in that Judgment (a combined royalty rate of 0.6% for the PanOptis Portfolio) was further leveraged by favourable comparisons between the quality of the portfolio before Birss J and the quality of the Optis Portfolio ([200], i - iii). The Judge noted that Optis’ assertion on the quality of its portfolio would have had very limited effect on a sophisticated counterparty, but it would have applied pressure against a smaller one ([200], iv).


General approach to negotiating licences: Apple


Apple claimed to follow a FRAND framework (called ‘Apple Framework’ in the Judgment). It was based on the following two starting premises (para 22 cited in [201]):

 

i) The smallest saleable patent practising unit (SSPPU) for cellular SEPs is the baseband chipset, where the functioning of the cellular standards is substantially practiced or embodied; and

 

ii) The proportion of the overall cellular declared SEP royalty profits that is allocated to the cellular SEP holders is determined to be no more than the profits of the baseband chipset.

 

The Apple Framework includes two steps to arrive at the licence rate for a portfolio (paras 27 – 28 cited in [201]).


Apple’s methodology involves attributing a price to the overall stack. Their approach was based on the smallest saleable patent practising unit (SSPPU). Apple argued that the baseband chipset, the SSPPU, contained the cellular functionality of the standards, and that this should frame the debate on the value. As an example, if the chip was valued at US$ 25 and the cost of production was US$ 20, the manufacturer’s profit is US$ 5. Apple argued that the baseband chipset manufacturer should pay for the licence out of the US$ 5 profit, and that this constituted the absolute limit payable by anyone ([212] – [217]). The Judge rejected this argument. He considered that there was no reason why the baseband chipset manufacturer would have to fund the licence fee to the stack out of the US$ 5 profit. It is much more likely that the chipset manufacturers would increase the price of their product to reflect the added value to the purchasers. It is wrong to assume that the chipset manufacturer would absorb the costs of the licence and not pass them on ([218]).


Apple defended throughout the trial the importance of a licensee's right to insist on a patent-by-patent review of any patent in an SEP portfolio ([206]), but this approach was not fixed but was regarded as an negotiating ploy ([207], ii). However, it cannot seriously be suggested that Apple failed to engage or failed to take the request for a licence seriously ([210]).


Apple insisted on a lump sum payment.


Whether the value attributable to the standards should be excluded?


The Judge did not accept Apple’s proposition that the SEP owner should be rewarded for the technology inherent in the SEP and not for any contribution the SEP made to the standard itself: when the SEP owner enters into the FRAND undertaking not to seek an injunction, this is a contribution going beyond the value of the SEP itself ([228]).


The comparable licences


Optis and Apple each produced 19 licences, but because of the heavy redaction little more can be discerned. The Judge noted in this part that to expect either party to concede, ex ante and in negotiations, that a given patent or a proportion of a portfolio was valid and/or essential would be ill-advised commercially ([245]).


The Judge held that use of comparables is inevitably a fact-driven exercise ([290]). While the readers may remember that in InterDigital v Lenovo [2023] EWHC 539 (Pat) Mellor J adopted an exclusionary approach with comparables, disregarding most and eventually relied on a single prior licence LG 2017 to derive all the rates in that Judgment, Marcus Smith J differed from that approach and considered that at least in this case, the comparables only have value if an inclusive approach is taken. Exclusions must be explained ([291]).


The Judge rejected the unpacking of both valuation experts, fundamentally because the nature of the comparables in this case has taken both far outside the zone of their proper expertise ([312]). There is an insurmountable difficulty with resolving three subjectivities in the unpacking ([314], [301]): the different rates at which royalties were computed (ad valorem, per unit, or lump sum?), cross-licences (Optis is not an implementer while Apple exchange cross-licences), future royalties and past releases. Both experts unpacked in accordance with their principal’s respective stances, not independently ([315]).


The (unconcluded) negotiations between Optis and Apple


[323] – [352] reviewed the negotiation history. On Optis, the Judge concluded that their approach to negotiation was inept, and that they were simply bad negotiators rather than playing ‘hardball’. Their offers were no more than a series of demands for money, not underpinned by any particular effort at persuading the purchaser that the price represented proper value ([354]). The Judge doubted whether even Optis knew what its thinking was. There was a great amount of incoherence ([354], iv). To the extent their offers could be understood ‘they were all over the place’ ([354], v). Apple did not on the evidence seek to game the system or put pressure on Optis through negotiating gamesmanship ([354], vii).


Regarding Apple, the Judge did not consider that Apple failed to engage or operated in bad faith ([357]). Apple would have departed from their Framework only very reluctantly ([359]). The Judge commented that some aspects of the Apple Framework were not pragmatically possible when seeking to agree terms for a portfolio of any size, such as trying to consider the technical merits of the individual SEPs or dealing with the patents on a patent-by-patent basis ([360]).


The Judgment in Unwired Planet (First Instance)


The Judge rejected the submission that Unwired Planet (First Instance) might properly inform his own determination of what is a FRAND rate. The principle in Hollington v Hewthorn ([1943] KB 587, Court of Appeal), interpreted by Hoffmann J is that ‘[i]n principle the judgment, verdict or award of another tribunal is not admissible evidence to prove a fact in issue or a fact relevant to the issue in other proceedings between different parties.’ ([363]). Although the Judge perceived no divergence in law between his approach and that in Unwired Planet (First Instance), he held that it would be impermissible for him to consider a factual finding in that Judgment as binding on him: Apple was not party to that litigation, and the evidence he has heard here was not the evidence in that litigation ([364], i, iii).


Was there hold up, hold out, and/or an abuse of dominance?


Hold out and hold up is intrinsic to any hard commercial negotiation for a licence ([366]). The Judge accepted that the contractually enforceable obligation against an SEP owner eliminated hold up in negotiations, subject to two qualifications: parties should in no way be discouraged from seeking to leverage their legal rights in commercial negotiations; and as the law in this area was only now being settled the risk of hold up being threatened effectively may not be discounted in the period up to the commencement of these proceedings ([368], i). But losing the threat of hold up does not mean that a significant control over the implementer’s ability to hold out has been removed: the threat of hold up remained in the period up to the commencement of these proceedings, and probably there is not such correlation between hold up and hold out ([368], ii).


The Supreme Court in Unwired Planet did not find that hold up or hold out was unlawful ([369]). They are undesirable ([370]). The absence of hold up and particularly hold out is likely to be an indicator of improper market power on one side ([372]).


The UK jurisdiction has articulated a legal regime which resolves the problems of hold up and hold out, as described in [1] – [24] of this Judgment. The combination of the FRAND promise on the part of an SEP owner and these courts’ reluctance to impose an injunction for infringing an SEP when an implementer expresses their willingness to enter into a licence on FRAND terms remove any serious prospect of hold up ([377]). The answer to hold out is that the FRAND licence whose terms the Judge sets does not incentivise hold out, by ensuring that past infringements are fully paid for and that interest on the payments accrues ([379]).


Answering the submission of the parties, Apple appears to have claimed that Optis’ conduct prevented meaningful negotiations, but this was not considered even to come close to being abusive, and even assuming some kind of abuse by Optis the Judge did not see what loss Apple has suffered: the courts can award costs ([385]). Further, Optis is not a dominant undertaking either: by giving its promise to ETSI Optis cannot obtain an injunction for any declared SEP where the counterparty has expressed willingness to obtain a licence on FRAND terms ([386] – [387]).


Turning to Optis’ contentions on this point, it appeared to the Judge that any argument about hold out that goes beyond the terms of the FRAND licence needs first to assert that the hold out crossed the line from being legitimate to illegitimate, but the Judge much doubted that such a distinction exists as a matter of law: courts should not without good reason be drawn into policing the negotiations between entities in a market, and he knew of no cause of action that is constituted by an allegation of illegitimate hold out ([391]). These contentions are unfounded and legally irrelevant ([392]).


Optis v Apple Trial E (Part I): findings on specific issues and topics Optis v Apple Trial E (Part I): findings on specific issues and topics Reviewed by Henry P Yang on Friday, December 29, 2023 Rating: 5

No comments:

All comments must be moderated by a member of the IPKat team before they appear on the blog. Comments will not be allowed if the contravene the IPKat policy that readers' comments should not be obscene or defamatory; they should not consist of ad hominem attacks on members of the blog team or other comment-posters and they should make a constructive contribution to the discussion of the post on which they purport to comment.

It is also the IPKat policy that comments should not be made completely anonymously, and users should use a consistent name or pseudonym (which should not itself be defamatory or obscene, or that of another real person), either in the "identity" field, or at the beginning of the comment. Current practice is to, however, allow a limited number of comments that contravene this policy, provided that the comment has a high degree of relevance and the comment chain does not become too difficult to follow.

Learn more here: http://ipkitten.blogspot.com/p/want-to-complain.html

Powered by Blogger.