Trade Secrets sit somewhat awkwardly amongst IP rights.
To start, there is debate over the mere
status of trade secrets as an IPR.
Unlike other IPR,
their protection often lies in contract and tort law.
They also have the distinct disadvantage of generating relatively lower fees for the legal
professions and none for IP offices.
Did I mention they are also secret? However, interest in the topic appears to be increasing with institutions such as the
European Commission launching research programmes and consultations on the subject.
|
No secrets here |
At the
Workshop on Non‐Compete Clauses, Trade Secrets, and Mobility in Munich last week, organised in large part by
Karin Hoisl, a gathering of specialists on trade
secrets,
non-compete clauses (NCC) and labour
mobility gathered to discuss these issues.
This is where IP law and economics meets labour law and
economics.
Labour mobility is economically desirable due to its association with higher efficiency as it allows for better allocation of resources and higher levels of innovation. Stringent NCC or trade secret laws are said to reduce labour mobility as employees are legally or contractually restricted from moving between competitors. Trade secret and NCC law must strike a balance between protecting innovation and facilitating labour mobility.
To start, we looked at field evidence of trade secrets.
Ivan Png presented his
work on trade
secrets non-competes and mobility of engineers and scientists. Png’s work is
unique in that he looks at the empirical side of trade secrets using
field data.
He measures protection of trade
secrets with a new index of trade secrets law as well as the doctrine of
“inevitable disclosure”.
Stronger trade
secrets protection reduced mobility by 1% of scientists and engineers with
postgraduate degrees but not those with less education.
Michael Risch presented his take on American
data on trade secret disputes collected by
Almeling.
The
defendants in these cases are typically employees (62%) or business partners
(27%.) It is also very hard to lose a case, as the owner of a trade secret, on the
basis of not having “independent economic value.”
However, employees often win on the basis
that the owner did not take reasonable precautions.
Trade secret owners need an average of two
precautions (e.g. employee agreements or passwords) in order to have taken
sufficient precautions.
On the legal side,
John Howe discussed the highly entertaining Australian term “BOOT” which is the “better off
overall test”.
BOOT suggests that, in
collective bargaining agreements (unions), employees shouldn’t be worse off
than the industry standard.
This prevents
employers from using the collective bargaining process to strengthen trade secrecy
clauses and disadvantage employees.
Sarah Turner called trade secrets the
“
Cinderella” of the IP world, as misappropriation appears to be getting
worse.
She discussed her recent
EC report, with Robert Anderson, which finds that current law in Europe is fragmented.
In many places, Italy for example, it is very
difficult to prevent the public from entering the court during hearings.
This presents a problem as the trade secret
loses its value when it becomes public.
Turner also pointed to an interesting balance in
injunctions. The granting of permanent injunction can significantly extend the
protection of a trade secret.
A
permanent injunction creates a potentially interminable legal support against
the use of a trade secret this could extend beyond the natural life of the
trade secret.
To account for this,
Danish courts, for example, may grant a injunction lasting a few years which
may be insufficient commercially.
Damages
may also be an unsatisfactory remedy as defendants may be judgement proof.
William Van Caenegem discussed the trade off
between NCC and trade secrecy laws.
Courts may interpret NCC more favourably in recognition that the trade
secrets law was relatively weak.
Is this
still the case?
[Thinking like an economist, Merpel asks how these balances
might affect incentives to innovate.]
In some exciting
experimental economics,
Michael Vlassopoulos (with David Gill and Victoria Prowse)
looked at cheating in the workplace. Participants in an online experiment received
bonuses either randomly or correlated with effort. He finds that subjects who received the
random bonus are more likely to cheat.
More productive workers cheat more.
Workers are not concerned only about the amount they received, but at
the way it was achieved – a notion of procedural fairness. As disgruntlement is
a motive to misappropriate trade secrets, perhaps ‘fairer’ reward schemes would
reduce theft.
My favourite quote of the day: “where there is data, there are economists.” [Merpel says this appears to be the case
regardless of the importance of the issue.] However, trade secrets may still be a bit of a pumpkin as researching them is a challenge. The search for the owner of the glass boot continues.
Are you sure that Van Caenegem is a Kat fan?
ReplyDeleteCave Ca(e)ne(ge)m!