Chaired and introduced by Lord
Justice Richard Arnold, this year’s edition of the Annual Spring Conference
organised by the Centre for Intellectual Property and Information Law at the
University of Cambridge addressed the question: ‘Is IP Good for Our Health?’.
With thanks to Dr John Liddicoat for photos of the conference and to Dr Kathy Liddell for those of her cats!
It would appear that Prof Lionel
Bently (CIPIL) chose the theme serendipitously, as many of the topics
considered how best to incentivise pharmaceutical development – which, of
course, relates to the current spread of and response to coronavirus.
Dr Liddell introducing the conference theme |
Dr Kathy Liddell (University
of Cambridge) began by setting out the day’s objectives and set the Conceptual
Framing, including the overarching motivation of bringing together
practitioners and academics to share information, explore research, and promote
academic shaping of the field in practice. This reflects a key research
interest within CIPIL of assessing whether various legally-based incentives for
pharmaceutical innovation are working well enough.
She then explained the underlying
cost-benefit argument justifying IPRs, in which these exceptional rights in a
competitive market are accepted in order to incentivise innovation to provide
social benefits. Even strident critics of IPRs such as Bessen & Meurer
accept the benefits they bring in the pharmaceutical industry. However, we
can’t take the IP system for granted, and Dr Liddell moved to identifying a
number of key questions which help in evaluating the overall conference theme,
including how we should interpret terms such as ‘good’ – but also considering
whether asking the question is helpful, even if we don’t think we will get all
the answers.
With these in mind, the conference
turned to consideration of two of the main incentives for research: Patents
& Regulatory Exclusivities.
Katherine Moggridge presenting |
Katherine Moggridge
(Three New Square), who acted on behalf of appellants ICOS, discussed Actavis
v ICOS, the most recent case in the UK Supreme Court to address
obviousness. The case concerned a dosage patent relating to a second in class
drug, the use of tadalafil under the brand name CIALIS for the treatment of
erectile dysfunction.
She explained that this goes to the
heart of the matter: when and how do we assess what is ‘not obvious to a
person skilled in the art, having regard to any matter which forms part of the
state of the art’? Should this be considered to apply only at one ‘inventive
step’, or should the court apply a holistic assessment?
She then gave an overview of the case
at first instance and in the Court of Appeal, where opposing conclusions were
reached. In line with Lord Justice Jacob’s point in Actavis v Merck, the
Court of Appeal stated that – in certain circumstances – there is nothing
inventive about routinely-taken steps even if the actual outcome had not been
predicted.
While ICOS made an application for
leave to appeal to the Supreme Court, Mr Justice Henry Carr determined in
related proceedings as to a preliminary injunction that there was no realistic
prospect of the appeal succeeding as it related to an ‘entirely routine step’
i.e. the determination of dosage.
In light of this, it was surprising
that the Supreme Court granted permission to appeal. Lord Hodge spent a lot of
time considering the statutory question of assessment of inventive step,
including giving a list of relevant factors. These include whether the approach
was obvious to try, and whether it gave unexpected results. For the first time,
the burden and cost of research appeared as a factor. More interestingly, he
also included the nature of the patent, while acknowledging the settled
approach of the EPO that dosage patents are capable of validity.
Katherine emphasised that there was
perhaps a bit of a missed opportunity to give inventive step a shakeup, saying
that there has now been a full year of cases going through the patent courts
since the judgment and it feels like business as usual. The question of at what
stage contribution can or should be divorced from innovation – with this case
concerning a drug which was held not to have cleared the inventive step hurdle,
but which did also make a technical contribution to the art in the sense of dosage,
side effects, and commercial success – is perhaps for another day!
Lord Justice Arnold commented
the presentation by asking how we should strike the balance between innovation
and unfair monopolies. Of course, we want researchers to be incentivised to
tackle COVID-19, but the question is whether patents are the most appropriate
way to do so.
Trevor Cook |
Trevor Cook (WilmerHale)
then gave an overview of regulatory exclusivities in the EU and US, mainly
focussing on data exclusivity and market exclusivity. He noted that
supplementary protection certificates aren’t really a form of regulatory
exclusivity, as they require a basic patent and their legislative framework was
designed really to incentivise the development of new molecules rather than new
uses of old molecules. He also considered that more permissive case law such as
Neurim had been cut back by Abraxis and there are indications
that Santen will do the same, if the Advocate General’s Opinion is
followed.
He therefore primarily focused on data
exclusivity, or regulatory data protection, and market exclusivity, or orphan
medicinal product protection. In the former case, he argued that it should be
seen as a very different type of protection from trade secrets law nowadays
despite their common origin. In relation to the latter, he considered that it
is a much more absolute form of regulatory exclusivity than data exclusivity.
He then moved to explaining the 8+2+1
system in place in Europe since 2005 for human medicinal products, noting that
the assessment of ‘significant clinical benefit’ is not especially transparent.
However, he used the case study of ZYTIGA and how market authorisations were
granted nearly 20 years after the initial patents to illustrate that data
exclusivity can be a more effective incentive than patent protection. He then
noted the tailored regimes in place for Veterinary Medicinal Products, which
are geared towards promoting development of products for bee and fish health –
especially in the wake of Regulation 2019/6.
Dreaming of enhanced protection for Kat health |
Finally, he considered the question of
‘similarity’ in orphan exclusivity, as the condition of ‘same or similar’ product
applies in Europe by comparing Imatinib and Nilotinib. In the US, it is only
the same drug – not similar – where there are restrictions.
Overall, his overview stated that SPCs
don’t incentivise new indications, and regulatory data protection is most valuable
as an incentive to seek the first market authorisation for a product which has
weak, old or non-existent patent protection. The question of ‘similarity’ in
orphan provisions is a bit murky, but overall, regulatory exclusivities may
offer greater incentives than patents in certain circumstances.
The third topic of the day was Drugs,
Competition Law, Parallel Trade and Brexit, which Lord Justice Arnold
identified as some of the limits on IP law which seek to provide balance in the
system.
Chris Stothers
(Freshfields Bruckhaus Deringer) brought insight from his work as a
patent litigator, including challenging the basic idea of the market for a
given drug as (1) the patent owner having exclusivity, (2) the patent running
out, (3) many others jumping in, and (4) the price crashing as not actually
being the optimal strategy for a generics manufacturer. Instead, such a company
wants to be ‘first and alone’ on the market, with key – distinct but often
merged! - topics in the area including patented drugs settlements, patented
drugs discounts, and off-patent drug price rises.
Patented drugs settlements are often
considered exciting, but the cases aren’t throwing up many surprises. After the
Commission’s Pharma Sector Inquiry, which was followed by monitoring up to
2016, the big topic was ‘pay for delay’ settlements, where a generic company threatens
to launch imminently unless the innovator pays them a lot of money. Generics
(UK) for instance, was concerned with pretty old conduct, reflecting the
pace of competition law. Therefore, while we might have quite a few EU cases
coming out, they’re not really telling us much new. On the other side of the
Atlantic, the ongoing case of Baltimore v AbbVie is interesting as it
represents a challenge to differential entry settlements (i.e. where a generic
company is allowed to enter certain markets but not others). This may
ultimately put settlements at risk – but Chris emphasised that he doesn’t think
it will or should do so. He also identified another case prodding the edges of
competition law as Gilead, where the court said that there might be a
competition problem with ‘most-favoured entry plus’.
In relation to discounts and other
schemes for patented drugs, he criticised regulators’ approach in several
cases. In MSD/Remicade, the CMA didn’t make a definitive finding but did
tell the companies not to enter such an agreement again. Essentially, the CMA
said that the parties tried to make an anticompetitive agreement which didn’t
work on the facts. In relation to AstraZeneca, Chris considered that the
objection was basically that the company was insufficiently transparent – but
he said it was hard to see how it could actually be considered anticompetitive.
Finally, he saw the approach of the Italian Competition Agency and ultimately
the Italian Supreme Court in Pfizer as very difficult to understand from
an IP lawyer’s perspective. Using divisional patents after failing to file SPCs
may be anticompetitive, but that merely reflects what patents do in practice!
Lastly, he noted that the conference
was not so timely in relation to Pfizer/Flynn – as the Court of Appeal
was then still pending (see Tuesday 10 March’s judgment here). While there was clearly
an agreement between Pfizer and Flynn in breach of Article 101 TFEU to put the
price of a very old epilepsy drug up, the CMA chose to go after them on the
basis of Article 102 (abuse of dominant position). The Competition Appeal
Tribunal chose to say that a consistent framework is needed – even if the
parties have behaved badly. This case should clarify the point on when price
increases are abusive pricing or indicative of a cartel. The problems arising
here are typically nothing to do with innovation per se, but more to do with
market structure and regulation.
This presentation sparked some fairly
lively discussion, with Chris emphasising that patents are much less black and
white than they are typically considered. Instead, they are ‘grey’ in terms of
validity until a final court decision comes out. However, as Lord Justice
Arnold observed, we should try to promote out-of-court compromise – but Chris
identified that this is very difficult when we remove incentives to negotiate
by doing things like deeming differential entry settlements to be
anticompetitive.
However, he did note that just because
parties have agreed to a course of conduct, it doesn’t make them free of
competition regulation. There are other factors at play, especially when we’re
considering what is best for ‘our’ ‘health’ – and he said that often he looks
at cases and thinks, why else would that money have been paid if not for
nefarious anticompetitive purposes?
Following that discussion, Katharine
Stephens (Bird & Bird) flagged that there can be equally strong
feelings about her topic of ‘Exhaustion, Parallel Trade and Brexit’. This
concerns the balance between right-owners’ interests and the broader interests
of free and fair competition when talking about the point at which
right-owners’ control of goods expires in the sale of genuine goods. Firstly,
she identified two approaches: Betts v Wilmott and an implied licence,
and exhaustion, i.e. that IPRs are extinguished after sale. She then identified
national and international flavours of exhaustion and considered them in an EU
context.
Where there are harmonised rights,
there are typically harmonised rules as to exhaustion; however, Katharine
observed that the question of when it is legitimate to oppose further dealings in
the goods has been tested to destruction by the pharma community. This has been
done in a variety of ways, such as repackaging in different markets and
debranding – giving the example of Mitsubishi v Duma, where not using
a trade mark was determined to be affecting the function of the trade mark.
Following Brexit, it’s not clear
whether there is any opportunity to reconsider the rules. When EY produced a
Government-commissioned report on this, they made no real recommendations or
suggestions except to note that most stakeholders want the status quo to be
retained. Pharma companies argue that arbitragers make unfairly high levels of
profit just by moving goods around the EU, and that parallel import rules
encourage them not to supply to poorer countries as well as impacting safety by
making it hard to tell between genuine parallel imports and counterfeit
products. On the other hand, pro-exhaustion arguments turn on promoting
competition and consumer access; the NHS saves huge amounts of money every year
through purchasing parallel imports. Therefore, if we end up with a post-Brexit
regime of only national exhaustion, there may be drug shortages and increased
prices.
While the Intellectual Property
(Exhaustion of Rights) (EU Exit) statutory instrument would essentially
preserve the status quo from the UK’s point of view, the UK can’t do anything
about what stance the EU will take. The SI is also silent about goods imported
from third countries, though it makes provision for the retention of existing
EU caselaw on lack of recognition of international exhaustion unless the
Supreme Court decides otherwise. This point prompted discussion on the scope of
such retention: where will it leave the UK if it adopts EU caselaw which is
overtaken by developments by the CJEU? Lord Justice Arnold gave an explanation
of what this may mean in response to a question at the end of Katharine’s
presentation, including warning that the position of the European Union
(Withdrawal Agreement) Act 2020 could result in leaving the UK open to having
many different interpretations of the same caselaw if any court in the three UK
jurisdictions can apply its own interpretation.
Stay tuned for Part 2, on the afternoon's proceedings!
With thanks to Dr John Liddicoat for photos of the conference and to Dr Kathy Liddell for those of her cats!
Conference Report: CIPIL 2020 (Part 1)
Reviewed by Sophie Corke
on
Thursday, March 12, 2020
Rating:
No comments:
All comments must be moderated by a member of the IPKat team before they appear on the blog. Comments will not be allowed if the contravene the IPKat policy that readers' comments should not be obscene or defamatory; they should not consist of ad hominem attacks on members of the blog team or other comment-posters and they should make a constructive contribution to the discussion of the post on which they purport to comment.
It is also the IPKat policy that comments should not be made completely anonymously, and users should use a consistent name or pseudonym (which should not itself be defamatory or obscene, or that of another real person), either in the "identity" field, or at the beginning of the comment. Current practice is to, however, allow a limited number of comments that contravene this policy, provided that the comment has a high degree of relevance and the comment chain does not become too difficult to follow.
Learn more here: http://ipkitten.blogspot.com/p/want-to-complain.html