This Kat hopes you enjoyed the first instalment of her coverage of CIPIL 2020. We now turn to the second half of the conference.
After lunch, the discussion turned to Precision
Medicine, Drug Repurposing & the Next Steps for Competition Law, with perspectives
from academia. Dr Mateo Aboy (University of Cambridge) discussed
whether recent case law is ‘good’ for precision medicine with an empirical
analysis of patent judgments in the US and Europe. He moved through his
presentation with the aid of a series of articles he had written or co-written,
starting by defining precision medicine as the tailoring of medical treatment
to the individual characteristics of each patient. This could be explicit,
based on biomarkers and medical responses, or implicit, using AI.
These Kats support collaborative research |
By mapping key US Supreme Court
decisions, including Myriad, Mayo and Alice, he was able to
illustrate that sometimes the supposed effect of court decisions actually comes
from other factors. For instance, the standard of novelty/non-obviousness was
already taking care of the issue of isolated gene patent activity; indeed,
these patents are also not being granted despite the legal position not being
the same as in the US. He did note that it is hard for patent attorneys to
draft around Myriad – especially small entities – despite its intention
to be a fairly narrow decision. Indeed, 85% of Myriad-based rejections
were actually directed to patent claims which extended beyond isolated DNA.
This indicates that patent examiners are using caselaw in a different, wider
way than that intended by the Supreme Court.
By contrast, the impact of Mayo indicates
that it has incentivised ‘crafty drafting’, as it is easier to obtain a patent
for a method of treatment than a method of diagnosis. Its other effects include
increased uncertainty, increased prosecution costs, and lower proportions of
successful small entities. Alice has had the most significant impact
overall, and interestingly he noted that there has been a significant
difference in the way in which Alice has been interpreted and applied by
the USPTO depending on the priorities of its head. His overall assessment of
these three cases was that there has been the least impact on the largest
entities with the greatest resources.
This presentation also sparked a discussion
including, from Lord Justice Arnold, a question of whether it should really be
easier and more desirable to obtain patent protection for a method of treatment
than a method of diagnosis. Mateo answered that it is not that patenting a
method of diagnosis is illegitimate in the US, but that the Mayo conditions
are more onerous – while also noting in response to another question that the
kinds of claims available will drive methods of business, alongside other
factors encouraging investment in US firms such as the availability of capital.
The next empirical presentation came
from Dr John Liddicoat (also University of Cambridge) on
whether the EU incentive for drug repositioning has been effective with an
observational study. This looks at rates of repositioning before and after the
introduction of the +1 incentive on 20 November 2005 using the EMA dataset of
all drugs approved since 1995. This gave another view on the issues introduced
earlier in the day from Trevor Cook’s perspective as a practitioner. John
framed the issue by talking about how drug repositioning offers a cheaper,
faster and safer means of addressing medical issues than developing new
compounds, while patent protection works much better in the pharmaceutical
context for new compounds. Second-use patents are often a weak incentive
because their protection is narrow and they are challenging to enforce if valid
because of cross-label use. A case in point is Warner-Lambert v Generics
(UK).
However, applications for second-use
patents are increasing, so there must be various other incentives and
efficiencies at play. When examining the data on the +1 – non-patent -
incentive, it appears that there has only been a 2.6% - i.e. non-statistically
significant - increase in repositioning. The change in the number of times each
drug was repositioned was also not statistically significant. However, some
drugs have been repositioned many times, such as Humira at 23 times – and an
overall rate of ~45% of drugs being repositioned. It may be that off-label use
is a factor which disincentivises formal repositioning.
Reforming the repositioning incentive
is one option, such as adopting the US +3 system. However, John argued that
because rates of repositioning have remained fairly stable before and after the
introduction of the +1, it’s arguable that the +1 system itself gives a
windfall to companies which would have repositioned the drugs anyway. Policy
changes should rely on cogent evidence of cost-effective incentivisation of
innovation, so it doesn’t appear that an increase in the term of protection
would be merited at this time; equally, repealing the +1 would be an option
only if we could work out how much it would cost and confirm that it is not
spurring innovation at the moment.
Lord Justice Arnold observed that, in
relation to Warner-Lambert, we should avoid drawing conclusions from
strategically poor litigation choices – as they may have succeeded in a
narrower claim to peripheral neuropathic pain had it been tried at trial. All
three courts which heard the case agreed there could be a valid second medical
use for inflammatory pain, so it doesn’t indicate that such patents are invalid.
Finally, John argued in favour of
getting more creative overall with incentives, and to keep in mind that big
macro-variables are also at play, such as the impact of the global financial
crisis on pharmaceutical research.
Wolf Sauter and Lord Justice Arnold in discussion |
The final topic of the day was Global
Health, Alternatives to IP, Concluding Talk & Discussion with the
penultimate presentation from Wolf Sauter (Free University of Amsterdam)
in his academic capacity (rather than officially representing his
regulatory perspective from the Netherlands’ Authority for Consumers and
Markets). He gave an overview of a recent practical paper, ‘Reconciling
competition and IP law: patented pharmaceuticals and dominance abuse’¸ from
the Dutch insurance-based healthcare system’s perspective. In the Netherlands,
other forms of care are financially crowded-out because of the high cost of
drugs to insurers. One solution to such issues could come from the potential
interface between IP and competition rules which currently apply in
parallel.
He recalled the recent Generics case
as a welcome instance of anti- and pro-competitive effects being balanced, as assessing
e.g. a breach of Article 102 TFEU (abuse of a dominant position) can be
particularly difficult in the pharmaceutical context. For instance, the
methodology of determining what a ‘fair price’ is messy, difficult, and
resource-intensive for regulators, as well as engaging ideological market
regulation arguments.
Reconciling competition and IP law must
take incentives to innovate into account, such as in excessive pricing cases
like Pfizer/Flynn, which Chris Stothers talked about earlier in the day.
This includes a whole range of subsidiary factors like market definition and
dominance, the fragmented market power of Dutch insurers as purchasers compared
to national health systems with public price intervention, whether pharmacy
preparation should be seen as substitutable, and whether off-label use is part
of the market. The promotion of market competition by means of joint purchasing
initiatives or international collaboration appears merely aspirational at
present. However, the Netherlands should not be afraid of closing some
loopholes such as the orphan regime criteria, or indeed opening some others
such as endorsing pharmacy preparation. In any case, regulators must at least
try to enforce competition law while taking innovation into account, not least
to develop greater experience.
Lastly, in response to an audience
question, he explained the European Competition Network framework and suggested
that the Commission allows the Netherlands to take innovative competition
regulation approaches due to its relatively small size. It can therefore serve
as a form of prototype for other Member States, while also having its own
characteristics such as a lack of a domestic pharmaceutical manufacturing
industry and the effects of the single point of entry to a reimbursement
system.
Rochelle C. Dreyfuss (NYU)
gave the concluding remarks for the day, considering how the IP system
should be fine-tuned to ensure public access. While it may be tempting to go to
inventive step for reform, as the tap turning the stream of patents on and off,
it also defines the relationship between generations of innovators so should be
treated carefully. She then moved to summarising and commenting on the earlier
presentations, including giving a US perspective on regulatory issues such as
balancing benefits to US consumers with harms to the countries of origin in
parallel import cases. Similarly, she indicated in relation to Aboy’s
presentation on US case law that the balance between proprietary and access
interests in the patent system is distorted. Solutions to problems like these –
and the incentivisation of treatments which are not likely to be profitable –
must be imaginative and recognise that the money that comes from IPRs is not
the sole factor in driving innovation. She then gave the example of the WHO’s
FluNet as an instance of international collaboration between private
enterprise, government and charities which bears potential to be encouraged.
Following the presentations, Lord
Justice Arnold sparked a discussion on compulsory licensing and tailored
remedies, noting that eBay v MercExchange essentially introduces de
facto compulsory licensing. He gave the example of a tailored injunction he had
imposed in Edwards v Boston Scientific, where the IPR specifically had
to be balanced against the right to life of patients for whom the infringing
device was the only suitable treatment. By contrast, a Swiss court deciding the
same issue rejected that approach.
Rochelle responded that the incentives
are different for medical devices to drugs, because companies don’t want to
launch a new drug in the absence of an injunction against a future infringing
market entrant. Assessing compulsory licensing is a hard question which
intersects with other topics of discussion throughout the day such as the
right-holder’s consent requirement for parallel imports and exhaustion. Prof.
Sauter then gave a competition perspective on these issues, saying that
compulsory licensing could be used as a competition remedy independently from
and in parallel to TRIPS provisions.
The last strand of discussion turned
back to the conference topic, including whether ‘good for our health’ means
‘achieving fair returns for pharmaceutical companies’. A suggestion of
FRAND-style provisions was not especially popular in the room, and one audience
perspective from a non-pharma patent attorney was that changing the patent
system to better-accommodate pharmaceutical products risks unacceptably
distorting the system for all other inventions. Another suggestion was that an
entirely parallel pharmaceutical patent system should be created – with the
conclusion being that while a variety of possible solutions are available,
simply convincing industry, practitioners and government of any need for change
is one of the biggest hurdles.
With thanks to Dr John Liddicoat for photos of the conference and to Dr Kathy Liddell for those of her cats!
With thanks to Dr John Liddicoat for photos of the conference and to Dr Kathy Liddell for those of her cats!
Conference Report: CIPIL 2020 (Part 2)
Reviewed by Sophie Corke
on
Friday, March 13, 2020
Rating:
No comments:
All comments must be moderated by a member of the IPKat team before they appear on the blog. Comments will not be allowed if the contravene the IPKat policy that readers' comments should not be obscene or defamatory; they should not consist of ad hominem attacks on members of the blog team or other comment-posters and they should make a constructive contribution to the discussion of the post on which they purport to comment.
It is also the IPKat policy that comments should not be made completely anonymously, and users should use a consistent name or pseudonym (which should not itself be defamatory or obscene, or that of another real person), either in the "identity" field, or at the beginning of the comment. Current practice is to, however, allow a limited number of comments that contravene this policy, provided that the comment has a high degree of relevance and the comment chain does not become too difficult to follow.
Learn more here: http://ipkitten.blogspot.com/p/want-to-complain.html