What happened to the "long tail" theory of commerce on the Internet?


More than 15 years ago, with Amazon.com already on the ascendant, all talk was about how the Internet promised to liberate commerce for both sellers and purchasers. There was no more prominent expression of that optimism than Chris Anderson’s notion of the long tail (“The Long Tail: Why the Future of Business Is Selling Less of More”, 2006, here). However, if you are a Kat reader under the age of 35, you may not even recognize the term.

Since the euphoria of that time, the attitude towards “the long tail” has become more measured, bordering on skeptical. As one observer has stated, we are actually in an era of the “short head” rather than the “long tail”. What is all this talk about anatomy about? Read on.

Consider the following graph. Lots of occurrences regarding a small number of items are likely to happen within the bounds of the head on the left, far fewer occurrences regarding a greater number of items at the tail sloping rightward.

As applied to products, the basic notion is that the Internet worked a fundamental change. In the bricks and mortar world, where physical shelves dominate, the limits of space meant that only a limited variety within a given product category could be offered for sale to the physical customer (the “head”). The name of the game was to try and get your product on the shelf: No shelf, no exposure, no sales.

However, product offerings on the Internet are not constrained by the limits of physical space. Thus, while, in the Internet world, there will continue to be an abundance of sales of the leaders within a product category, the consumer also now has more abundant opportunity to purchase lesser known items (located at the tail). As a result, it is argued, the sales of such niche products, which individually may each be in low demand, can collectively amount to a substantial quantity, provided that there is both adequate supply and are distribution channels to provide such products.

In this way, the Internet seemed to promise a greater number of product offerings, redounding to the benefit of both the supply and demand sides of the relationship. On the one hand, niche product offerings could flourish, while, on the other hand, purchasers could enjoy access to these niche products.

As reported, Anderson took notice of research by Professors Erik Brynjolfsson, Yu (Jeffrey) Hu, and Michael D. Smith They argued that, with respect to the book business, Amazon.com enjoyed substantial sales of less prominent, even obscure books, i.e., niche products located at the tail, which previously were not likely to be offered for sale in bricks and mortar stores.

The idea was that information technology had materially lowered the search costs for such products. E.g., gone was the need to visit numerous second-hand book stores (if they even exist in your area) in the hope that some obscure publishing pearl might be discovered. Search was now to be done in front of the computer screen, enabling more efficient results.

The problem was that when researchers looked for instances of the long tail in action, more and more they are becoming hard-pressed to find them. This Kat conducted his own search and could not find a critical mass of studies that seem to validate the notion. To the contrary, research seems to point to the opposite. A 2018 report summarized by Professor Serguei Netessine in “The Long Tail Theory, Debunked: We Stick with What We Know”, here, describes the situation as follows:
The big message is we didn’t really find any evidence of the long tail effect, and that goes contrary to the theory and contrary to a few studies that were done before us. We found that, if anything, you see more and more concentration of demand at the top.
Take movies, especially the streaming platforms as exemplified by Netflix. [Merpel notes that in the current lockdown environment, the only platform more important than Netflix is Zoom.] Yes, there are more and more movie offerings, so indeed, the number of niche offerings, i.e., the tail, is getting longer. However (at least in a non-COVID-19 world) the actual time that one devotes to watching movies has not really increased.

So, are viewers more likely to watch more of these obscure titles, i.e., the tails, or stay within the comfort zone of hits and blockbusters? Netessine opts for the latter—
…[W]hen people search for what to watch in this increasing product variety, they tend to gravitate much more towards hits. We attribute it to the fact that, first, it’s hard to search this huge product variety. Second, even if you rely on some kind of a recommendation system, which every company uses now, recommendation systems are pretty basic. They only recommend something that somebody else has already watched, so they’re not going to recommend to you niche movies all that much.
From this perspective, gravitating to niche offerings, at least to streamed movies, does not seem to be manifesting itself as the long tail theory predicted.

OK, but what about selling things? Nettesine focuses on the role of recommendation algorithms, whose task it is to get before the customer what she is presumably looking for. Here, as well, niche products may not fare as well as hoped.

This is because, as he explains, such algorithms rely (albeit, not exclusively) on previous purchases. But that is precisely the problem for a niche product: how do you get purchased in the first place? And, in the absence of that initial purchase, how can one fashion the algorithm to reach such niche products?

The upshot is that “[a]s consumers are deluged with a dazzling array of choices, they tend to stick to brands they know.” Seen in this way, the strong brand remains the enemy of the niche product. The theory of the long tail viewed the Internet as the platform for ameliorating this state of affairs. But it does not seem to have quite worked out that way.

The supply of niche products may well increase. However, the behavior dynamics of consumer demand does not appear to have changed in respect to the role of brands, particularly strong brands. This seems to be the case, even as we are no longer constrained by the physical limitations of shelf space. Short head or long tail?

By Neil Wilkof

Top picture by Hay Kranen, who has released it into the public domain.

Bottom picture by Peretz Partensky and is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-Share Alike 2.0 Generic license.

What happened to the "long tail" theory of commerce on the Internet? What happened to the "long tail" theory of commerce on the Internet? Reviewed by Neil Wilkof on Sunday, April 05, 2020 Rating: 5

5 comments:

  1. Of course, a problem with on-line searching is that if you don't know the name of the obscure item, it will be very difficult to find it. When I was in professional practice, this could be a real problem when researching new technology whose terminology hadn't been universally established. More recently I couldn't find any miniature multi-pin electrical connectors on line to replace a faulty one on my electric bike. Only after posting an enquiry on an electronics forum did I discover that they are known (in China at least!) as "car connectors", and was able to get an exact replacement.

    ReplyDelete
  2. Another example of a long tail is the different types of restaurant available in a place. A very small town will have an Indian and Chinese. A larger one will also have an Italian. A city will also have Thai, Brazilian etc. The internet is a global city that allows the demands of the specialist to benefit the mainstream by making more options economically viable, and importantly this serves an anti-monopoly function in keeping the products and suppliers diverse in every field. Unfortunately consumers have no idea of how to maximise this effect and so benefit themselves and the population as whole and so their true economic and political power is still unrealised

    ReplyDelete
  3. I was unaware of Tan and Netessine's article, so thanks for sharing it, and for the useful summary!

    You might also find a recent article of mine interesting:

    https://scholarship.kentlaw.iit.edu/ckjip/vol19/iss1/10/

    I address the long tail on page 19-22. I reflect on how the concetration of interent users' attention in a 'short head' affects viewpoint diversity and the distribution of cultural influence in the public sphere.

    All the best to everyone out there in IP world at this strange and difficult time.

    ReplyDelete
  4. One reason is that the limited space on the 'shelf' has been replaced by the limited space on 'page 1'; and like the shelf, big players will pay to be put on page 1, either directly or through SEOs.

    That said, there is far more choice out there than there used to be, and I certainly have bought things from non-branded mfrs (with greater or lesser success); in this regard is suspect the long tail is dominated by Chinese manufacturers producing generic versions of 'head' electricals, clothing, etc, rather than niche products per se.

    ReplyDelete
  5. I do like one of the paragraphs from Henry Fraser's conclusion section of his article in as far as it addesses 'progress':

    "Over the past 25 years, the cultural turn in copyright scholarship has
    amply demonstrated that there is more to copyright than merely balancing
    incentives to create against the need for access to works. The qualitative,
    cultural effects of the law matter. If we truly believe that copyright law
    should be calibrated to promote ‘progress’, then we should take into account
    its effects on the distribution of cultural and communicative power; on
    democratic discourse and individual self-authorship; and on the
    inclusiveness and diversity of the cultural milieu. The cultural turn has
    produced a rich and productive normative framework for evaluating the legal
    and institutional parameters that organize and shape creative activity."

    I think it is important to have a concrete definition of 'progress' (see for example https://www.cairn.info/revue-d-economie-politique-2011-1-page-93.htm#)

    Copyright like everything else should be made subservient to some defined idea of progress so that the greater good is not undermined by IP rights

    ReplyDelete

All comments must be moderated by a member of the IPKat team before they appear on the blog. Comments will not be allowed if the contravene the IPKat policy that readers' comments should not be obscene or defamatory; they should not consist of ad hominem attacks on members of the blog team or other comment-posters and they should make a constructive contribution to the discussion of the post on which they purport to comment.

It is also the IPKat policy that comments should not be made completely anonymously, and users should use a consistent name or pseudonym (which should not itself be defamatory or obscene, or that of another real person), either in the "identity" field, or at the beginning of the comment. Current practice is to, however, allow a limited number of comments that contravene this policy, provided that the comment has a high degree of relevance and the comment chain does not become too difficult to follow.

Learn more here: http://ipkitten.blogspot.com/p/want-to-complain.html

Powered by Blogger.