As the September 17, 2016, survey published in The Economist, “The rise of the superstars”, points out--
“Silicon Valley is a very different place from what it was in the 1990s. Back then it was seen as the breeding ground of a new kind of capitalism—open-ended and freewheeling—and a new kind of business organisation—small, nimble and fluid. Companies popped up to solve specific problems and then disappeared. Nomadic professionals hopped from one company to another, knowing that their value lay in their skills rather than their willingness to wear the company collar. Today the valley has been thoroughly corporatised: a handful of winner-takes-most companies have taken over the world’s most vibrant innovation centre, while the region’s (admittedly numerous) startups compete to provide the big league with services or, if they are lucky, with their next acquisition.”As a result, these companies have passed on at least some of their R&D and innovation to third party start ups. Thus--
“….[C]corporations are, in effect, outsourcing some of their tech R&D to the startup world. This is true not only of non-tech companies that do not understand the tech world but also of big tech companies that do some of their R&D in-house but leave some of it to the market to get the best of both worlds. Big companies have much to gain from contracting out their R&D to startups. They can make lots of different bets without involving their corporate bureaucracies. But startups also have a lot to gain by selling themselves to an established company that can provide stability, reliability and predictability, all of which can be hard to come by in the tech world.”This “symbiotic relationship” might not be a source of concern with respect to R&D and innovation save for the fact that, as the article points out, studies are showing that startup activity has declined to a level not seen since the 1970’s, with more startups dying than are being created. Unless one assumes that this quantitative decline has no relationship with a decline in the aggregate availability of potential valuable technology, this current state of affairs suggests that there simply may be less innovative activity taking place at the startup level.
What is more certain is that these hi-tech superstars are accumulating more and more cash in their coffers, and they are using these sums to acquire startups and their technology, but from a diminishing pool of startups. It is no wonder, therefore, that the dream of (nearly) every startup is to be the object of a successful exit. Both sides would appear to win: the startup cashes out, enriching its investors, owners and at least some of its employees, while the superstar has acquired potentially valuable technology and manpower.
But there may be a broader societal loss lurking behind this seeming win-win situation. After all, unless the superstars are in parallel increasing the scope of their own internal innovation research, the upshot would seem to be that, as the number of startups decline, sooner or later there will be less aggregative R&D and innovation taking place. This Kat does not underestimate the ability of these superstars to adapt themselves to changing circumstances. But moving from an (at least) partial reliance on startups to internally-based R&D and innovation may be a bridge too far for some, especially if the corporate culture has moved on from an obsession with innovation to an obsession with market dominance.
One need only think of the recent announcement made in September 2016 by Bayer to acquire Monsanto, seeking to join an agro-tech giant with a company rooted in excellence in chemical products. Given the already small number of dominant companies in each of these industries even before the merger, concerns about the anti-competitive effect of the proposed acquisition were immediately raised. In response, the two companies pointed to the enhanced ability of both to do more and better innovation (creating "an innovation machine", in the reported words of the CEO of Monsanto). Not a few figurative brows were furrowed upon hearing this. But if R&D and innovation becomes more and more an internal, rather than an external activity, the ability of superstars to carry out an increasing share of their innovative research will be crucial not only for the companies but for the economic well-being of society more generally.
ReplyDeleteThe situation which Neil Wilkof describes is perhaps not unusual in the history of industrialization. At the beginning of each wave of industrial development there were a big number of small laboratories, pharmacies, manufacturer etc. Only, one did not call them start-up at that time. If you want, global players such as Bayer, Merck (I mean the German company Merck KGaA and its former U.S. affiliate which is today Merck, Inc.), Boehringer Ingelheim, Pfizer, Siemens, Ford and many others were initially “start-ups”. Not to talk about companies which were born in a garage like Apple and Microsoft. They became the big companies which we all know but many others disappeared or were taken over by bigger players during the time. We have seen this in the past two decades also in the field of gene technology or biotech.
Nevertheless, I believe that we should not be too pessimistic. When new innovative approaches and development emerges, there is always the chance of new start-ups provided that the surrounding conditions are favorable for them. Where does R&D usually take place at first hand? At university institutions. What they need is a good funding from the government but also from private industry and private investors allowing them to carry out independent scientific research in the spirit of Alexander v. Humboldt and others.
It is certainly true that if a company such as Bayer acquires another company such as Monsanto, there will be somehow a concentration of R&D activities within one company. However, I seriously doubt that this will lead to less R&D activities as such. Big companies are under immense pressure to remain innovative. They have to launch continuously new innovative products on the market. In the field of pharma and agriculture, they must not launch them in a frequency like consumer good industry has to do in fields like chocolate or beverages. R&D for innovative products in the field of pharma and agriculture is very expensive and risky since many attempts can fail. This means that industry’s own R&D departments do a lot to find innovative compounds by themselves. However, in most cases, that will not be sufficient to keep the pipeline of new innovative products filled up. Therefore, collaboration with start-ups and university institutions is key as well as in-license promising compounds which have been developed by such institutions. One should also keep in mind that start-ups usually do not have the know-how or ability to bring complex products such as pharma- and agriculture products to the market in a big number of countries given the highly regulated environment.
Another question is certainly how to create a new start-up initiatives out of R&D activities coming from university and to support such approaches. R&D is usually a long process, full of trial and error activities, requiring not only a lot of money but also time !!!. Once a start-up depends on the goodwill of their investors, they have to deliver something promising in a certain period of time. Not every outstanding researcher is also a good manager of a company and the other way around. It is certainly not easy to find the right balance but it works perhaps more often than we may think. One reason why there is now less R&D activities in the Silicon Valley could be that investors are much more carefully when deciding which start up is worth to be supported. There have been so many companies which never developed successful products or services. Another reason could be that there are today also more interesting competitors in other parts of the world. Maybe the R&D environment in the field of IT has changed and requires to find new paths.
Christian Schalk
This article represents the personal opinion of the author.